Typically, we study games under given rules, but we can also examine the optimal rules of the game, i.e., mechanism design. For example,

Typically, mechanism design is a broader concept than contract theory, which focus more on bilateral relationships (principal-agent problems).

There are two classes of contract design problems:

There exists information asymmetry under both problems, however, for Moral Hazard, principal can convince agents to exert effort with the appropriate incentives, and for Adverse Selection, agents' behavior (outcome) is not affected by incentives, but by her type.

Hidden Action (Moral Hazard)

Principal-Agent Model (Linear Contract Case) [2]

<aside> Sequence of events

  1. The principal offers a linear contract: $w(q) = \alpha + \beta q$.
  2. The agent chooses whether to accept or reject the contract (with a outside option $U$).
  3. If accept, the agent chooses effort $a \in A \equiv[0, \infty]$.
  4. Output $q=a+\varepsilon$ is realized, where $\varepsilon \sim \mathcal{N}\left(0, \sigma^{2}\right)$. </aside>

Consider the first-best case, where the principal chooses the action $a$ to solve

$$ \begin{array}{ll}{\max _{a, w(q)}} & {\mathbb{E}[a+\epsilon-w(q)]} \\ {\text { s.t. }} & {\mathbb{E}\left[-e^{-r(w(q)-c(a))}\right] \geq U. \quad \text { Individual Rationality (IR) }}\end{array} $$

<aside> Optimal Solution

$a^{*}=\frac{1}{c}$ and $w(q)=-\frac{\ln (-U)}{r}+\frac{1}{2 c}$.

Moral hazard occurs when the principal cannot choose and observe the agent’s action. Because the principal cannot enforce a particular action, she must provide incentives to the agent. Note that there are two extreme cases of the contract:

<aside> Optimal Solution

$a(\beta) = \frac{\beta}{c}$, $\beta^{}=\frac{1}{1+r c \sigma^{2}}$, $\alpha^{}=\frac{\bar{u}}{r}-\frac{1-r c \sigma^{2}}{2 c^{2}\left(1+r c \sigma^{2}\right)^{2}}$, where $\bar{u}=\ln (-\bar{U})$.